Bitcoin and stone money: Anglophone use of Yapese economic cultures, 1910-2020

Article available at Finance and Society open access.


Recently parallels have been drawn between Bitcoin and Yapese stone money. This article focuses on Fitzpatrick and McKeon’s (2019) exploration of similarities and differences. The analogy between Bitcoin and Yapese stone money is based on proposed commonalities that are inaccurate, ill-defined, and/or trivial. However, this does not signal a need to refine the comparison, but rather a need to reconsider the rationale for attempting it in the first place. Recent attempts to redefine Yapese stone money using terminology from the field of cryptocurrency reproduces a longer textual history in which writers from the Global North have misrepresented Yap for pedagogic or polemic convenience. Examples include works by William Furness III, John Maynard Keynes, Milton Friedman, and influential macroeconomics textbooks, such as N. Gregory Mankiw’s Macroeconomics. This history features frequent colonialist tropes of Yap as well as the erasure of histories of colonial violence and power. More caution should be exercised in the study and pedagogic use of Yapese economic cultures, and greater effort should be made to center Yapese voices, acknowledge colonial contexts, and reflect positionality and uncertainty.

Excerpt: Marc Shell, Money, Language and Thought

Recognizing money of the mind involves locating monetary form in linguistic exchange […] That money and language are complementary or competing systems of tropic production and exchange suggests that money not only is one theme, metaphoric content, or “root metaphor” […] in some works of language, but also participates actively in all. My argument is not that money is talked about in particular works of literature and philosophy (which is certainly the case), but that money talks in and through discourse in general. The monetary information of thought, unlike its content, cannot be eradicated from discourse without changing thought itself, within whose tropes and processes the language of wares (Warensprache) is an ineradicable participant.

 

Roundtable: Has Economics Failed?

Tom Clark and Chris Giles, writing for the Financial Times, debate the big picture of the economics profession. A few other FT writers respond.

Here is the contribution from Diane Coyle, the Bennett Professor of Public Policy at the University of Cambridge:

The Discipline Suffers from its Lack of Diversity

The debate about the state of economics is a bit surreal, to an economist. Tom Clark says economics is “a profession in a defensive mood”. Only if it is defensive to point out that what some critics are describing bears scant resemblance to economics. I’d go so far as to say there is economics, which is what academics, consultants and many officials do; and something almost entirely different, “economics”, an ideological construct deployed by some politicians and polemicists. The critics are attacking “economics” and calling it economics (when they are not calling it neoliberalism).

This is deeply frustrating. Partly because it would be marvellous if critics could accept that areas of the discipline such as market design, behavioural economics, industrial organisation, auction theory, data and techniques for policy evaluation, institutional economics, construction of major historical data sets et cetera are not just the few useful contributions identifiable in “a far-fetched vision of omnipresent and flawless markets”. On the contrary, areas such as these form the bulk of the work economists do.

But it is frustrating as well because there are certainly valid criticisms of economics. My top concern is its social composition. It is a largely male, white and posh profession — not a foundation for good social science, whose questions, hypotheses and data need to be rooted in society. The male dominance reflects both culture and the unusually narrow criteria for advancement in the academic profession, where only five journals really count. Other people would highlight further weaknesses, but then economics is a living science, looking at a constantly changing society, and there is a lot to learn.

And here is a snippet from the contribution of Mariana Mazzucato, Professor of Innovation and Public Value at UCL:

[…] the assumption that price reflects value means that we end up constantly correcting gross domestic product for the priceless activities it ignores (caring services at home, environmental damage, quality of life). And similarly, those activities which do have a price, but are just moving things around rather than creating value, get included (eg. most of the financial sector).

My suggestion is that before we add happiness indicators, we first take out rents. This would cause the GDP of some countries to drop drastically and for new questions to be asked about the “direction” of growth, not only its rate.

Article: The Return of Economic History?

By Guillaume Calafat & Éric Monnet, trans. Lucy Garnier.

The reasons behind the loss of influence of economic history are well known. However, for a long time, it held pride of place in both disciplines. In the nineteenth century, economics had a strong place in history departments because it was an integral part of the national narrative. Later, economic history was pursued in very different ways by both Marxist history and the Annales School. The economic dimension to the historical dynamic was considered essential in the Marxist tradition, because it was primary in all social relations, and among Annales historians, because it was a key element for analysing long-term changes (technical, commercial, entrepreneurial, etc.). Historians’ interest in economic history then waned due to a radical critique of the primary nature of economic relations and to greater focus on discourse and representations (of the world, the market, etc.). At the end of the 1970s, this was coupled with a critique of statistical tools and the lack of neutrality of quantitative approaches. In short, cultural history and the history of representations progressively came to replace economic history – paradoxically, just as the dissemination and progress of IT tools seemed to offer new measuring instruments and new possibilities for analysing economies of the past.

Full article here.

Review: Cents and Sensibility

“Cents and Sensibility” is less a critique of economics than a critique of using “only” economics. It is especially relevant in the presence of ethical doubt. Should there be a limit to prescription drug prices? Is it right for universities to mislead the public about SAT scores, or about why they give financial aid? Such questions indeed require sensibility as well as cents. This is a bracing, original work, reminding us that economics was never supposed to be about the math but rather about the stories it tells about our lives.

Full review at The Washington Post.

CfP: Economics and Science Fiction

Vector is pleased to invite proposals for short articles (2,000-4,000 words) exploring science fiction in relation to any and all themes related to economics, as well as economic history, economic sociology, economic anthropology, economic humanities, finance, political economy, IPE, and other adjacent disciplines and fields.

Please submit abstracts of 200-400 words to vector.submissions@gmail.com by 31 March 2018. Full CfP here.

See also:
Economics in SFF
Economics for SF Researchers

Poem: Some Money

A prose poem by Mairéad Byrne.

Some Money
I haven’t spent some money for a while.  It’s time ah I spent ah some money.  I’ve paid the bills.  I did that ah Monday.  Early.  I paid the bills.  It’s not like money.  It’s not cash and it’s not illicit.  It’s just something you ah have to do.  Like you’re doing the right thing when you pay the bills.  You’re just doing what you have to do.  No-one will thank you.  Or know.  Though if you don’t do it WHAM.   In the slammer.  Out.  Cut off.  Whatever.  Guys in suits coming towards you with cold smiles.  Yeah.  So I pay the bills.  But I haven’t spent some money for a while.  The kind you spend on stuff you don’t so much need or can’t afford but you get it anyway.  Because it’s there and you’re there. Though that’s kind of like the bills.  It makes sense later on.  The kind of spending I’m getting at is the opposite. You buy the thing.  It’s beautiful.  You want it.  Or you just want it.  PAM.  You click.  Snap down your card. You have it.  Or you have it soon.  It comes.  But then the other part, the cost, is hanging out there somewhere, shelved like a big husk in a warehouse, until it gets swept up in your cycle and comes swinging in with the bills.  And you deal with it.  You deal with it.  But there’s something about that part, when you have the thing but the cost is kind of out there, amputated,  a hulk in wait.  It’s not a sexual thrill but it is something.  Kind of postmodern.

Robert Shiller on narrative economics

Listening to Robert Shiller’s online lectures, I’ve often half-written him an email in my head on some point. I distract myself and have to rewind. If you go to the “Drafts” folder in my brain, a third of them are to Robert Shiller.

Essentially, I wanted to tell him something about the humanities. I’m not sure what. Maybe just that the humanities exists. Professor Shiller can be quite perplexing. On the one hand, he’s a hugely influential figure in behavioral economics, and behavioral economics is the field with a great track record in confronting the more brutal absurdities of mainstream economics. On the other hand Shiller still is, frustratingly, very much an economist.  Although behavioral economics may ameliorate some of the features of scientistic finance and economics which humanities scholars tend to find so frustrating, it never goes nearly far enough.

So I’m happy to see this article from him!

Behavioral economics was economics with an input from the psychology department. Every department has its own tool kit for approaching research; we were very much influenced by psychology. Maybe a little sociology, maybe a little anthropology, but nevertheless all social-science fields.

I’m starting now, with my more recent work, to think that we have to look at the humanities as well. There is something difficult to formalize about human beings, but something that we nonetheless have to understand, and I think one way to do that is with an approach that I’m calling “narrative economics”: taking economics and adding the study of the narratives that people transmit.

If Shiller is serious about narrative economics, he may want to give poststructuralism a whirl, and see if he can shake the set of intellectual habits that make “human instinct for storytelling” seem like an appropriate way of introducing an endeavor of this kind.

But it’s another step in the right direction …

See also: Shiller’s ‘Narrative Economics’ paper (2017).

 

Excerpt: Ellen Meiksins Wood, Democracy Against Capitalism: Renewing Historical Materialism

In one form or another and in varying degrees, Marxists have generally adopted modes of analysis which, explicitly or implicitly, treat the economic ‘base’ and the legal, political, and ideological ‘superstructures’ that ‘reflect’ or ‘correspond’ to it as qualitatively different, more or less enclosed and ‘regionally’ separated sphere.

This is most obviously true of orthodox base-superstructure theories. It is also true of their variants which speak of economic, political and ideological ‘factors,’ ‘levels’ or ‘instances’, no matter how insistent they may be about the interaction of factors or instances, or about the remoteness of the ‘last instance’ in which the economic sphere finally determines the rest. If anything, these formulations merely reinforce the spatial separation of spheres.

Other schools of Marxism have maintained the abstraction and enclosure of spheres in other ways – for example, by abstracting the economy or the circuit of capital in order to construct a technically sophisticated alternative to bourgeois economics, meeting it on its own ground (and going significantly further than Marx himself in this respect, without grounding the economic abstractions in historical and sociological analysis as he did). The social relations in which this economic mechanism is embedded – which indeed constitute it – are treated as somehow external. At best, a spatially separate political power may intervene in the economy, but the economy itself is evacuated of social content and depoliticized. In these respects, Marxist theory has perpetuated the very ideological practices that Marx was attacking, those practices that confirmed to the bourgeoisie the naturalness and eternity of capitalist production relations.

Bourgeois political economy, according to Marx, universalizes capitalist relations of production by analysing production in abstraction from its specific social determinations. Marx’s approach differs from theirs in his insistence that a productive system is made up of its specific social determinations – specific social relations, modes of property and domination, legal and political forms. This does not mean simply that the economic ‘base’ is reflected in and maintained by certain ‘superstructural’ institutions, but that the productive base itself exists in the shape of social, juridical and political forms […]